I think it is quite safe to say that macroeconomists are slightly baffled at the moment. Firstly, the GFC was a shock to most free market advocates. The horrors of recession and the perceived failure of capitalism convinced many that we need more government, not less. However, the post-GFC outcomes have been equally puzzling and there are still so many unanswered questions: If markets are efficient, where do bubbles come from? If inflation is ‘everywhere and always a monetary phenomenon’,[1] why has it taken so long for inflation to pick up after Quantitative Easing programs? If stimulus programs work, why was growth so sluggish? Given the failure of the standard explanations, maybe its time to resurrect an idea that has been ignored by mainstream thought: Please enjoy my attempt to briefly explain the Austrian Business Cycle Theory (ABCT).[2]
Unfortunately, the intricacies of the theory are quite detailed and require a lot of explanation, but a very loose outline would go something like this:
All people depend on price signals to coordinate their behaviour. One of the most important price signals is the interest rate. The natural interest rate represents the intersection of the savings and investment curves and coordinates the time scale of investments. Basically, low interest rates allow for more ‘long term’ or ‘round-about’ projects. High interest rates lead to more ‘short term’ projects.
A quick example would be useful here: Suppose you want to start up your own small business. In order to run this business, you need some office space. So, should you rent or purchase? The interest rate will be crucial in your decision. A low interest rate makes debt affordable. This might convince you to purchase. If interest rates are high, you will probably rent.
Similarly, interest rates also coordinate capital consumption. Should you buy a car or keep catching public transport? Do you buy a house or do you keep renting? It might depend on the interest rate.
So, low interest rates lead to long-term projects. Long-term investments require capital. Hence, if interest rates are low, there will be higher demand for capital, so the price of capital increases. Higher prices incentivise production; so capital-producing industries will expand.
Let us now introduce a central bank. Suppose the central bank increases the money supply and puts new money into the banking system. Firstly, interest rates will ‘artificially’ decline. This sends a false signal to investors that long-term investments are cheap. Simultaneously, it tells consumers not to bother saving and that they can buy a house.
It’s important to note that the newly created money won’t immediately generate inflation, because all the money is being funnelled into buying capital assets, causing capital asset prices to rise. Again, this causes increased capital production. All of this leads to the boom: The share-market picks up, debt increases, house prices accelerate and cranes dominate the skyline. It is only when the newly created money goes into the pockets of consumers that we start to see inflation – this time lag is a crucial element for this theory to make sense. Nevertheless, eventually the new money causes inflation in the prices of inputs and ultimately final products.
Inflation leads to increasing production costs (wages rise, input prices rise) causing an unexpected profit squeeze. Suddenly, businesses feel like they need to borrow some more money to get through a rough patch. Simultaneously though, banks start getting nervous. If inflation is higher than interest, the banks will actually be losing money on their loans. So, they raise interest rates – just at the time when businesses are under unexpected pressure!
Long-term projects are suddenly becoming unaffordable, so demand for capital assets grinds to a halt. Price growth slows, and then reverses. This causes the boom-time expansion of capital production to go into reverse and jobs are lost. Meanwhile, people who bought capital in the boom time suddenly hold assets that are worth less than the debt they owe to the bank! This brutal adjustment process inevitably leads to bankruptcies, failing financial institutions, and ultimately a recession.
Does this all sound a bit familiar? The crash of 2007/2008 was preceded by a period of very low interest rates, a bubble in the housing market and an associated boom in the financial sector and stock market. Rising interest rates eventually popped the bubble, causing the GFC and all the ensuing chaos.
It is important that we do not ignore ideas that are out of step with mainstream thought. By engaging with the ideas of the past, we can strengthen our knowledge of present theory and understand how economics has developed and evolved as a science. More importantly though, underneath the refuse of the bad economic ideas we throw away, we just might find a gem of brilliance that is worth dusting off and displaying in a new light. For what it’s worth, I think the ABCT is one of those gems.
References
[1] Milton Friedman, The Counter-Revolution in Monetary Theory (1970)
[2]The outline of the original idea was suggested by Ludwig von Mises in his book The Theory of Money and Credit (1912). It was fleshed out by Friedrich Hayek in his book Prices and Production (1933). Mises developed the theory further in his later works, such as Human Action (1949). In recent years a number of economists, mainly concentrated at George Mason University, have attempted to re-enliven this theory and apply it to recent recessions.
Image sourced from https://mises.org/library/why-mises-and-not-hayek
The views expressed within this article are those of the author and do not represent the views of the ESSA Committee or the Society's sponsors. Use of any content from this article should clearly attribute the work to the author and not to ESSA or its sponsors.
Founding sponsors
Partner
Platinum sponsors
Gold sponsors
 
 
 
 
Silver sponsors
 
 
 
 
Affiliates